Economies without Growth for 20 Years: A Common Bond between Japan and Africa
Africa
Column
Director General, Area Studies Center
PDF (64.5KB)
Despite
its
decline,
Japan,
the
world’s
third
largest
economy
and
a
country
of
advanced
technological
prowess,
should
not
be
mentioned
in
the
same
breath
as
Africa’s
economies,
which
stagnate
at
the
bottom
of
the
pyramid
in
the
world—or
so
one
may
think.
However,
of
all
the
economies
in
the
world,
the
Japanese
economy
and
African
economies
have
one
thing
in
common:
an
arrest
in
growth
for
20
years.
The
regional
GDP
of
Sub-Saharan
Africa
in
nominal
dollars
had
seen
almost
no
growth
from
1981
to
2002.
The
average
yearly
growth
rate
never
reached
1
percent.
Meanwhile,
Japan
has
not
recovered
at
all
from
the
Heisei
recession,
which
began
in
1991.
As
of
2011,
its
GDP
hovers
around
5
trillion
dollar
or
500
trillion
yen.
While
many
countries
have
experienced
a
“lost
decade”
of
long-term
stagnancy
in
economic
growth,
it
is
extremely
rare
that
it
lasts
for
over
20
years.
As
a
result,
a
generation
that
has
not
experienced
economic
growth
in
Africa
and
Japan
is
now
responsible
for
their
societies’
direction.
In
the
case
of
Sub-Saharan
Africa,
its
population
multiplied
during
the
20
years
of
absent
growth.
As
a
result,
per
capita
GDP
was
reduced
roughly
by
half.
Profound
long-term
poverty
set.
Development
economics
today
took
shape
and
advanced
academically
as
economists
analyzed
the
unprecedented
situation
of
a
further
decline
in
income
in
an
already
poor
region.
The
phenomenon
of
a
serious
stagnation
in
production
value
even
as
the
population—and
thus
the
labor
force—grows
is
not
easy
to
explain.
There
must
be
some
powerful
causes
at
work
to
stall
economic
growth.
For
development
economists,
Sub-Saharan
Africa’s
impoverishment
was,
so
to
speak,
a
“natural
experiment”
they
could
not
have
imagined.
Oxford
University’s
Paul
Collier
described
it
as
“a
gold
mine
to
economists”.
We
researchers
in
this
field
have
been
competing
to
dig
this
gold
mine
to
search
for
factors
that
hold
back
the
economic
growth
of
Sub-Saharan
Africa.
If
you
think
about
it,
Japan
has
been
in
an
economic
slump
for
20
years
now.
For
the
Japanese,
Africa’s
story
is
no
longer
remote.
If
the
findings
of
development
economics
are
universal,
then
the
causes
suppressing
growth
in
Africa
that
we
have
discovered
can
be
applied
to
explain
Japan’s
economic
stagnation.
One
cause
raised
by
many
scholars
around
the
world
for
Sub-Saharan
Africa’s
economic
malaise
is
its
“landlockedness”.
The
African
continent
has
over
50
countries,
and
so
it
has
the
most
landlocked
countries
of
all
the
regions
in
the
world.
Because
those
countries
do
not
touch
the
sea,
they
do
not
have
ports,
making
trade
inconvenient
and
dragging
down
their
economic
growth
rate.
Of
course,
this
explanation
does
not
apply
to
Japan.
Another
theory
is
the
“black
market
premium”.
Because
mistakes
in
monetary
policy
should
hold
back
investments,
the
idea
is
to
measure
the
difference
between
public
exchange
rates
and
the
black
market
exchange
rates.
However,
this
theory
does
not
fit
Japan’s
situation.
Many
papers
have
also
sought
to
study
the
assumption
that
it
must
be
a
low
level
of
education
that
hinders
economic
growth.
This
factor
does
not
concern
Japan
either.
Tribal
divisions
and
social
conflicts
are
also
unknown
to
Japan.
Growth
regression
analysis,
the
methodology
that
studies
the
causal
relationship
between
such
factors
mentioned
above
and
the
economic
growth
rates,
is
itself
under
a
cloud
of
doubt
as
to
whether
its
arguments
have
been
correct.
Because
the
African
economy
experienced
a
boom
that
began
in
2003,
the
validity
of
many
of
the
ideas
that
have
been
developed
concerning
Africa
must
be
examined
again,
at
least
as
they
concern
the
GDP
growth
rate.
That
diminishing
returns
in
labor
took
place
in
Sub-Saharan
Africa
at
the
close
of
the
20th
century
is
certainly
a
fact.
Because
the
dependent
variable
of
growth
regression
analysis
is
per
capita
GDP,
what
should
be
clarified
is
not
economic
growth
rate
but
the
difference
between
population
growth
rate
and
economic
growth
rate,
i.e.
diminishing
returns.
However,
it
is
a
question
whether
growth
regression
analysis
has
clearly
focused
on
diminishing
returns.
Thus
economists
have
looked
instead
to
just
the
economic
growth
rate.
Furthermore,
there
is
a
difference
between
factors
that
are
generally
accepted
as
influencing
economic
growth
rate
and
the
factors
that
actually
move
the
economic
growth
rate.
During
the
1990s,
when
debates
about
governance
were
prevalent,
many
experts
argued
that
the
biggest
barrier
to
economic
growth
in
Sub-Saharan
Africa
was
bad
governance.
However,
this
argument
cannot
explain
how
Africa’s
economy
suddenly
began
to
take
off
in
2003
at
a
speed
rivaling
China’s
economy.
Economic
growth
still
took
place
without
any
tangible
improvement
in
governance.
Of
the
factors
economists
have
discussed
affecting
economic
growth,
there
is
one
that
applies
to
Japan:
“openness”.
In
their
paper,
Sachs
and
Warner
argue
that
the
degree
of
exposure
to
international
markets
determines
the
rate
of
economic
growth
(Jeffrey
Sachs
and
Andrew
Warner,
“Sources
of
Slow
Growth
in
African
Economies,”
Journal
of
African
Economies,
Vol.
6
No.
3,
Oxford
University
Press,
1997).
The
share
of
foreign
trade
(export
plus
import)
in
GDP
of
Sub-Saharan
Africa
after
the
1980s
fell
to
the
40
percent
level
and
persisted
there.
Sachs
and
Warner
argue
that
this
was
a
result
of
mistakes
in
trade
policies,
and
demonstrate
that
there
was
a
significant
relationship
between
the
degree
of
foreign
trade
and
per
capita
GDP.
While
Japan
is
called
a
trading
nation,
its
degree
of
trade
dependence
is
remarkably
low.
Import
and
export
as
a
percentage
of
its
GDP
is
about
30
percent,
the
same
level
as
the
United
States.
The
degree
of
trade
dependence
of
European
countries
bound
to
one
another
in
the
European
Union
Economic
Area
is
easily
over
50
percent.
China’s
degree
of
trade
dependence
is
80
percent,
South
Korea’s
is
100
percent,
Malaysia’s
is
200
percent,
and
Singapore’s
is
300
percent.
Japan’s
figure
is
far
from
the
world
average,
and
it
is
also
not
growing.
Japan’s
economy
is
extremely
introverted.
The
biggest
theme
in
development
economics
since
its
inception
has
been
the
role
of
trade.
Thus
foreign
trade
provides
a
hint
about
Japan’s
growth
potential.
While
Japan’s
neighbor
South
Korea
presses
forward
with
FTA
negotiations
even
if
it
means
sacrifices,
Japan
is
consumed
with
inward-looking
debates.
Its
degree
of
foreign
trade
dependence
is
on
the
way
to
becoming
lower
than
the
United
States’.
Another
cause
for
Japan’s
economic
stagnation
may
be
the
loss
of
“demographic
bonus.”
The
graph
below
shows
the
working-age
population
(age
15-64)
as
a
percentage
of
total
population.
The
graph
includes
estimated
values
for
South
Korea
after
2010
provided
by
the
Korean
Statistical
Information
Service.
As
can
be
seen
from
the
graph,
Japan’s
figures
show
two
peaks,
in
1968
and
1992.
Demographic
bonus
is
reaped
during
the
period
when
the
ratio
of
the
working-age
population
increases.
Japan’s
period
from
1950
until
the
peak
of
the
first
mountain
reflects
its
period
of
rapid
economic
growth.
The
period
after
the
second
peak
corresponds
to
the
Heisei
recession.
Paul
Krugman
has
argued
that
labor
input
was
the
driving
force
behind
East
Asia’s
economic
growth;
technological
input
contributed
little
(Paul
Krugman,
“The
Myth
of
Asian
Miracle,”
Foreign
Affairs,
Vol.
73,
1994).
This
article
attracted
a
great
deal
of
controversy,
but
Krugman’s
assertion
is
believed
to
be
correct
when
it
comes
to
the
stall
of
the
Japanese
economy.
Krugman’s
argument
is
not
a
show
of
contempt
for
the
significance
of
East
Asia’s
economy.
Of
all
developing
countries,
only
East
Asia’s
export-led
economic
growth
achieved
full
employment.
It
was
economic
growth
that
consumed
the
labor
force
of
those
nations.
Furthermore,
because
the
energy
of
those
countries’
people,
their
greatest
asset,
was
thrown
into
production,
increasing
it,
only
in
East
Asia
was
gains
in
growth
heavily
distributed
to
workers,
equalizing
income
distribution.
However,
if
a
labor
force
capable
of
input
begins
to
decrease,
this
growth
pattern
will
also
decline.
In
Japan’s
case,
because
the
country
has
little
exposure
to
international
markets,
the
drop
in
domestic
demand
as
a
result
of
population
loss
is
a
direct
hit
on
Japanese
industries.
The
loss
of
demographic
bonus
is
not
a
phenomenon
endemic
only
to
Japan.
As
shown
in
the
graph
above,
South
Korea’s
ratio
of
working-age
population
is
expected
to
shrink
beginning
in
2016.
Experts
believe
China
will
reach
its
peak
in
the
working-age
population
in
2015.
If
the
same
phenomenon
that
took
place
in
Japan
also
occurs
in
the
two
countries,
East
Asia’s
prosperity
is
headed
for
a
finale
in
five
years.
The
aging
society
casts
a
pall
over
East
Asia.
I
believe
that
the
half
century
of
knowledge
accumulated
by
development
economics,
including
the
range
of
population
theories,
will
be
beneficial
for
the
revitalization
of
Japan.